Understanding the explosion of
health care cost isn’t rocket science. It is actually a trivial warm-up
exercise for the mind: as we eliminated, at least statistically speaking, a
growing number of once significant causes of death, more people reach an age
where they become more cancer-prone because their genetic coding turns less
stable, their immune system deteriorates, and mutations following from many
causes are less manageable. Malignant
neoplasms, also known as cancers, are the result. Although they account for
only about
13% of overall causes of death and likelihood of cancer deaths does not
increase with longevity – on the contrary, it declines significantly from a tipping point of
roughly 55 years of age – those afflicted today not only stand better
chances of successful therapeutic intervention but also are less likely to die
of other causes, clearing the way for longer survival rates at significantly
higher cost.
As the duration of our ability to
control malignant tumor cells increases with the advent of various
pharmaceutical and other therapeutic approaches, there is still no cure in
sight and cancer has remained a highly complex systemic disease requiring
multiple complex balancing acts.
These balancing acts quite often
are to be taken more literally than society would like. A small group of specialty
pharmaceuticals accounts for roughly 25
percent of all drug-related spending. A cancer patient in need of a few
targeted therapies can quickly run up a monthly tab in the five digits.In 2007, the overall costs of cancer — including treatment
and indirect mortality expenses (such as lost productivity in the workplace) —
was estimated to be $226.8
billion. Pressure is likely to increase and will demand answers to
questions society has long shirked as unethical – or, more to the point,
politically inconvenient to almost everyone: What price human
life? Who is to decide? And how to allocate the expense?
It is safe to assume that the
number of potentially remaining fairly trivial pharmaceutical discoveries is
rapidly declining. On the other hand, cost of regulation of a time-consuming
bureaucratic review and approval process has mushroomed. There is political
pressure to lower, certainly not to increase, the available period for patent
protection. After a
number of years even the most expensive drug is manufactured and sold as a generic at whatever
cost-plus formula the market will bear, but, despite recent
increases in the price level of generic drugs, sometimes but not always at
a significant fraction
of the sticker price afforded during patent protection. This is an aspect
separate from increasing doubts
about the equivalency of generic to branded drugs.
Because pharmaceutical companies set
their prices in accordance with a country’s purchasing power and, basically,
price elasticity, it is possible in some cases to source the same drug in an
emerging market for 10 percent or
less of its American price. The concept of parallel imports, of buying
abroad, may be limited by customs regulations but will not be stopped
altogether, except by driving up transaction cost.
All that said, while industrialized
nations spend about 10 percent of GDP on health care, only about five
percent of that accounts for prescription pharmaceutical
expenses. While society may have a duty to reward fair value
of effective pharmaceuticals, and needs to steer clear of disincentivizing
investment in research, alternative billing models will become inevitable
in the reasonably near term as innovative immune therapies are about to turn
certain types of cancer into the functional equivalent of a chronic disease,
stretching extreme therapeutic cost from weeks or months to several years.
We do not want insurers to
determine access to proven but costly life-prolonging medication, because
decisions would inevitably be made by accountants. Nor do we want
pharmaceutical companies to abuse temporary monopolistic power to determine the
price – and thus the value – of prolonged
human life. Nor can we leave it to patients to decide how much to pay for
added lifespans because, so long as they don’t pay, price does not matter to
them. No stakeholder in this matrix is capable of deciding the appropriate
price
The British NHS’s advisory body National Institute for Health and Care
Excellence (NICE) has recently fired a warning shot by declining to cover about
one-third of cancer medications
on account of price. Because pharmaceutical companies, with
profit margins between 25 and 50 percent, cannot afford the consequences to
their public image from playing hardball, alternative pricing models will need
to look at creative solutions such as contingency pricing tied to a therapy’s
success and to quality of life changes. They may involve package deals or
discounts in combination of various models.
One option sure to be popular
among pharma investors for handling this was recently demonstrated by the head
of Turing Pharmaceuticals who upped the price for its essential toxoplasmosis
drug Daraprim
by 5000 percent. While Daraprim is no cancer medication, toxoplasmosis can
be life threatening to immunosuppressed individuals as cancer patients often
are. This is a choice example of how to spawn ammunition for socio-political
backlash by outdated definitions of ‘free market’ business judgment in an
industry that never operated for a single day in a ‘free market’ but always
depended on the artificial creation of temporary legal monopoly by political
consensus.
But whichever way whoever wants
to turn it, creativity has limits: just years down the road, even the most
expensive cancer medication will have lost patent
protection.
No comments:
Post a Comment