A
specter is haunting the globe since the sixties – the specter of Social
Enterprise. All the powers of old have
entered into a holy alliance to exorcise this specter. Like all ‘holy
alliances’ of the past, they will fail, not least because it offers genuine
alternatives for communities that are really neither served by commercial
providers nor by government programs that produce results meaningful to their
needs. Social enterprises are created on the fault lines between market forces
and charity, between the necessity of averting unrest and discontent and the
imperatives of continuing to create opportunity on which a knowledge-driven
economy depends. Venture
philanthropy, CSR
and charitable
foundations, classic and also non-traditional cooperatives have
experimented for some time with a broad range of initiatives. They range from
microcredits to social direct investment to many versions of small-scale,
targeted help with self-help. Sometimes their underlying objectives include
social engineering and sometimes they do not.
But
overall, social enterprise is
here to stay. It is no threat to for-profit operations, nor does it erode
their realistically perceived market potential. Only at the fringes of
predatory capitalism (think sub-subprime mortgages, pre-paid credit cards
accruing fees greater than their ‘credit line,’ bad-faith insurance policies or
violations of implied consumer trust) need it be expected that semi-charitable service
to less than privileged target audiences, sometimes to the ultra-poor, would somehow
interfere with bona fide generation
of profit and other aspects of commercial shareholder value.
While
the traditional political left finds itself at a loss for effective solutions
and its reflexive reach for Big
Government and entitlement spending has failed resoundingly over
considerable parts of the twentieth century, isolationist concepts such as
opposition to free trade in North America or quasi-isolationist proposals
fashionable in Europe such as taxing machines or hard drives as “job killers”
do not resolve anything. Social enterprise attempts to put technology and
education to differently prioritized uses that ultimately all aim to put
existing tools and concepts to a smarter use with greater holistic value
creation for the public interest. It is not synonymous with volunteerism.
Political
and philosophical views about the proper role of government or the optimum size
and funding of the welfare state may well differ across many cultures and political
flavors. It will continue to make for die-hard election issues. What cannot
differ, though, because it operates on the very principles of a free market and
in the organizational, structural and legal forms and tools of private
enterprise, is the use of imaginative entrepreneurial means to effect
impactful social change. Whether one wants to proclaim socialism dead or simply
hibernating, the conclusion “if you can’t beat them, join them, they must be
doing something right” has been demonstrated more than impressively across all
the success stories of Eastern Europe as well as by the legacy of Deng Xiaoping,
the man who transitioned China from cultural revolutionary chaos to capitalist
juggernaut (yet
was also responsible for the 1989 massacre at Tienanmen Square) with all
its remaining environmental and civil libertarian issues. But one of Deng’s unforgettable
aphorisms is particularly memorable in this context: “Poverty is not socialism.
To be rich is glorious.”
In
response to that notion, social enterprise aims to create common wealth and
imaginative solutions to social problems by applying more than a single, P&L
based standard of priorities and yardstick for results. Perhaps this is not
necessarily true for the bottom line of each entity but as a global phenomenon,
social enterprise is a high-value-added contributor to micro- and macroeconomic
infrastructure and to targeted problem-solving in communities.
Social
entrepreneurs provide needed services at low cost and at a low margin. Once
their product is perceived as advantageous, customers quickly come to consider
it essential infrastructure – and it is common knowledge that low-margin,
high-volume transactions are not an inherently unprofitable proposition.
Whether it is politically correct to some or not, one may conclude that success
in this sector is primarily about the quality of ideas: human nature does not
value gratuity unless it can be shown to be also good business or to create practical
value by indirect means (for which the internet is an obvious example: while
parts of it are still struggling with long-term viability of their business
model, overall value creation has been such by near-universal consensus that
‘nickel-and-diming be damned.’). The internet as a variant of social enterprise?
You bet. It meets a dozen reasonable criteria for the latter:
(1) Creative financing
(2) Little or no short-term profitability but much short-term attention
(3) Little or no customer tie-up or obligation
(4) Few if any barriers to access
(5) Few if any aspects of prestige or exclusivity – rather, inclusivity is emphasized
(6) Intangible value creation exceeds monetary value creation
(7) If intangible value creation were properly accounted for, valuation would be astronomical
(8) Innovative service based on bridging differentials in knowledge and training
(9) Scalability
(10) Responsive to critical thought about social problems
(11) Embracing the complexity of diversity through innovation
(12) Redefines public interest
Accounting
for social value is challenging in that its valuation often requires
considering concepts of damages: loss or
damage avoided rather than profit accruing (on which GAAP
is ultimately based). At the root of this paradox lay a variety of reasons,
primarily simplicity of accounting standards and deep-seated reluctance to
engage with hypotheticals
– which every consideration of either concept inevitably
involves.
But
in assessing social enterprise, it is impossible to avoid a close and methodical
look at hypotheticals. How could one otherwise account properly for cost and
benefits of a policy that avoided civil unrest and disobedience, or that
facilitated access to education or medical care? It requires dealing with
what-if scenarios that are by their very nature speculative but nonetheless
extremely relevant. A classic example is the valuation of a war not waged. Irrelevant?
Speculative? Perhaps, but at the same time, common sense renders notions of
“relevance” here obsolete.
Social
enterprise is widely understood to aim at impact,
a non-financial goal that is still somewhat in search of a definition. To
measure impact, the Social
Reporting Standard (SRS) was developed 2008 in Germany. In the end, the
chief difference between commercial and social enterprise is the acceptance or
rejection of adequacy and significance of GAAP. Accepting conventional
accounting standards greatly reduces complexity and provides for clear and
simpler guidelines. Rejecting them as basically meaningless – how else would
you call a concept that declines to assign a value to most intangible factors
that so obviously make up the majority of matters of importance in life? –
necessarily leads one to call for a fundamental review of accounting as a tool
and of the manner it is relied upon.
Peer-to-peer
processes, open access and
open
technologies are closely related with the emphasis on overcoming
unnecessary functions of intermediaries. Even the function of social venture
capital has been adopted successfully by organizations like Ashoka.
Still,
social enterprise and entrepreneurship function above all within the realities
of any purpose-driven business organizations – for the sake of long-term
viability and sustainability, but also because allocation of limited resources
has to follow certain principles. Those principles may well have been distorted
in for-profit organizations by their often single-minded emphasis on
one-dimensional values, but have nonetheless proved
to be effective. The common ground with
for-profit entrepreneurship is that, as a fundamental operating premise, social
enterprise is not based on reliance on government, subsidies and regulation, primarily
because of government’s well-known and seemingly incurable deficits in productivity:
Experiments around the globe from 1917-1989 have testified to the resounding
failure of the creed that elected public officials with limited (or, even
worse, unlimited) terms who are advancing special interests are capable of or
even motivated for achieving effective and lasting solutions for significant
social ills. Based on this conclusion, social entrepreneurship, just like any form
of entrepreneurship, is seldom partisan, since political parties are
representatives of the statist and governmental universe, and operate through
its mechanisms, not through those of private enterprise. While their purposes
may reflect a broader variety of tangible and intangible benchmarks, social
enterprises are most successful where they embrace, not reject, forms of
organization and management that enable value creation, even if the valuation applied
to measure it far exceeds principles and practices commonly reflected in
financial statements.
In
other words, any value-creating organization basically needs to follow – with
appropriate concessions – methods similar to those already proved effective in
private enterprise in general, even though its specific tool set may be selected
through the prism of a considerable difference in values.
Because
it is often – and in indirect ways ultimately always – related to problems of
qualification, social enterprise is closely linked to educational issues.
Today’s educational system has failed a growing segment of society in terms of
access and attainment of de facto minimum standards: the era when someone with
a legally required minimum of education could still make an honest living is a
matter of the past. Once, a warehouseman needed to be strong and orderly to get
the job. Today, this will not happen without a substantial extent of computer
skills and technical literacy. Because the need for educational qualifications
is exacerbated by the impact of technologies that increasingly eliminate almost
any opportunities for unskilled and even low-skilled
labor, it stands to reason that any push by social enterprise to remedy
this outcome needs to address – or at least act as a catalyst for – the same
educational and technological deficiencies as they affect social, analytic
and navigational competencies in a knowledge- and service-based economy. A developed
society that spends as much as it does on retirement and health care (and their
subsidies), on security expenditures with marginal results at best, and on other
controversial projects, needs to start spending a lot more, and a lot smarter,
on cost-effective preventive measures and future opportunities for the entirety
of its current and potential workforce.
No comments:
Post a Comment